Five energy experts – to include
Adam Sieminski of Deutsche Bank – were recently asked for their
opinion of the future of oil prices. Four of them – of which one
was anonymous – were not particularly optimistic, while the fifth,
Dr Leo Drollas of the Centre for Energy Studies (UK), took a
position similar to that of Steve Forbes (editor and publisher of
one of the best business magazines in the world), who basically
feels that the fundamentals are working in favour of a fall in the
oil price.
Several years ago Dr Drollas discussed the oil price in a long
paper in PetrominAsia, where he made heavy weather of an often
quoted aphorism of his employer, Sheikh Ahmed Zaki Yamani, which
was that there were still plenty of stones available when the
Stone Age ended. Apparently this was intended to warn the
producers of oil that they should go easy where the oil price is
concerned, because if they didn’t, and the oil age appeared to be
approaching its final stages, they might find themselves the
not-so-happy custodians of a few hundred million tonnes of a
nearly worthless commodity.
As I noted in a following issue of that publication, when I am
confronted with this kind of talk, I’m inevitably reminded of
Billy Joel’s song ‘In a New York State of Mind’, because wherever
people like Dr Drollas may wander, their thoughts are inexorably
centered on the next oil price meltdown. Incidentally, such a
meltdown is plausible, but one of the reasons why John von Neumann
was called the best brain of the 20th century had to do with his
informing us that when considering this kind of prospect, some
probabilities/odds should be introduced. On the basis of his
recent ‘State of the Nation’ speech, it seems clear that President
Bush and his colleagues have been thinking along this line, and as
a result they are no longer disposed to bet the farm on a bear
market in oil.
THE HARDER THEY FALL
In December of 2005, on the Swedish TV program ‘Genius Speaks’,
a group of new Nobel Prize winners spent a relaxed hour
speculating on the human condition in the light of existing and
possible scientific advances. As usual, the economics laureates –
Edward Prescott of the U.S., and especially Finn Kydland of Norway
– revealed themselves to be hopelessly naïve about what is
happening in the real world, as compared to the fantasy worlds so
prominent in the papers and lectures with which they torment their
students. As compared to the other laureates, they displayed an
almost bizarre incompetence.
Fortunately, they were not requested to explain what could take
place in the event of an escalation in the oil price which
resulted in a barrel of oil trading for something in the
mid-to-high seventies, or higher. Had they been asked, however,
they would almost certainly have responded that a price of that
amount, if sustained, would speed up the production of large
quantities of synthetic oil from gas and coal, and in addition
more effort would be put into exploiting hydrogen and biofuels,
etc. What would not have been mentioned is the time factor,
because in mainstream textbooks, the huge quantities of synthetic
items required to depress the price of conventional resources can
virtually appear over night. They would also probably overlook the
fact that when the initial millions of barrels of non-conventional
oil and motor fuel appeared, they would sell at or near the same
price as the real thing.
Something else that would not have been ventilated is the
likely macroeconomic effect of an oil price rise, which is
fortunate, because comprehensive explanations of that perplexity
are absent from textbooks, and the available presentations are
generally without any scientific value.
This is why it was both useful and interesting to examine a
recent article in the Financial Times (February 3, 2006) by Martin
Feldstein (of Harvard University), the title of which was ‘America
will fall harder if oil prices rise again’. My recent papers
contain a few of Feldstein’s observations, but the important thing
is that Professor Feldstein – who ostensibly was on the short list
of candidates for the position of governor of the U.S. Federal
Reserve System – elected to place this article where it will be
noticed, instead of in one of those unread tracts gathering dust
in our academic libraries.
Feldstein confirms that “the economic slowdown that was widely
expected never occurred”. He does not say who was doing the
expecting, however on the basis of various written and spoken
remarks, Alan Greenspan was almost certainly somewhere in this
crowd. Feldstein concentrates his discussion on the effect of
movements in the interest rate on consumer spending in the U.S.,
primarily via the propensity to refinance existing mortgages. In
my recent lectures I have been especially concerned with the
impact of a wealth effect that could be attributed to what I
picture as an inevitable rise in interest rates that would move
these rates closer to some kind of ‘historical’ average. In
particular, I noted what this could mean for share (i.e. stock)
prices, as well as the behaviour of firms and consumers who are
faced with ‘rolling-over’ their loans.
We are assured by Professor Feldstein that mortgage refinancing
in the U.S. has peaked. He says that this follows from the Fed (=
Federal Reserve) raising interest rates in order to counter
inflationary pressures that remain from the rise in energy costs.
I have some reservations about the word “remain”, which implies
that in a future where the oil price might continue to rise, these
pressures can be permanently removed by a simple boost in the
‘discount rate’. Something that needs to be emphasized here is
that things have gone so well in the U.S. that many observers have
concluded that the Fed can always attain the (market) interest
rates they desire by simply tinkering with the rate at which they
loan money to banks, however this is for the most part an
illusion.
Considerable attention was also directed by Feldstein toward
the large decrease in saving that has taken place, and the
concomitant increase in consumption. This rise in consumer outlays
more than offset the fall in incomes that (ceteris paribus) might
have accompanied the increased payments abroad that are
necessitated by higher oil prices. In addition, this unusually
strong consumer spending induced a higher physical investment.
What Feldstein did not point out though was that this spending
involved a large import component, and this might eventually have
negative macroeconomic consequences (due, among other things, to a
sizable dollar devaluation.)
The latter unpleasant scenario was avoided because foreigners
continued to purchase very large amounts of U.S. bonds, and to
purchase them at low interest rates. Professor Feldstein almost
certainly understands the interior mechanics of this arrangement
better than me, because when I was teaching macroeconomics during
the l980s, I assured my students that a regime of very low
interest rates, accompanied by a declining dollar, meant that the
huge inflow of foreign capital – at that time Japanese – could dry
up at any time, in which case the U.S. would be faced with a
painful adjustment or even a or a full-fledged recession.
Feldstein used the term “lucky” to describe the escape of the
U.S. from the consequences of excessive consumption (and excessive
debt), however as he admits “it would not be so lucky if a big oil
price increase happened now”.
THE BAD NEWS PRINCIPLE
Two academics who were (and perhaps still are) not worried
about any damage that could be inflicted on the U.S. economy by
high oil prices are Robert B. Barsky and Lutz Kilian. In one of
those unread journals referred to above, they tell us that
“disturbances in the oil market are likely to matter less for U.S.
performance than had commonly been thought” (2004).
Noting that this conclusion follows an econometric analysis –
where the emphasis should usually be put on the syllable ‘con’ – I
reminded myself once again that despite some cockeyed opinions to
the contrary, empirical work in economics can never take the place
of theory. But even so, of the thousands of papers that in one
form or another originate every year in academia, this is one of
the few that makes a systematic attempt to judge the impact of oil
price movements on the macroeconomic price level, employment,
productivity and economic growth. I am also generous enough to
believe that the reason they concluded that in general the effect
of oil price increases tends to be exaggerated, is because over
the period of their investigations (1970-2003), with the exception
of the first and possibly the second oil price shocks, they were
dealing with ‘spikes’ instead of sustained escalations. Of course,
a spike from the present oil price (of slightly over $60/b) to the
mid-seventies could be devastating for many persons in every part
of the world, since changes in the oil price – and particularly
upward movements – influences all energy prices.
There is “no support for the notion that increased uncertainty
leads to a sharp fall in investment that in turn contributes to a
recession”, the two authors tell us. What they mean by that is no
econometric evidence, although it might be suggested that
intelligent readers of the business press would be wise not attach
any merit to econometric game-playing. Thus I suggest that we
amend their observation to read ‘increased uncertainty can lead to
a sharp fall in investment that – if sufficiently sharp – can
contribute to a recession’.
Admittedly, some other conditions might have to be present,
such as those mentioned in the previous section, however the
economics here is really very simple: uncertainty functions in
such a way as to boost discount factors, which as we all know from
Economics 102 has a negative effect on physical investment because
it means a large reduction in the (expected) present value of
distant revenues. It is no more than common sense that investors
who could accept a certain (or nearly certain) return of 8%,
desire e.g. 11% when confronted with uncertainty because they feel
that something might go drastically wrong.
My favourite finance guru is Paul Erdman – beginning with his
novel ‘The Silver Bears’ (which was filmed and contained a
brilliant musical background), and more germane his pop-finance
book ‘What’s next’ (1988). Erdman’s rather special use of the
English language was never far from my thoughts when I was writing
my international finance textbook (2001), which I suspect is the
reason why an unidentified reviewer accused me of making an easy
subject difficult (although I suspect that in his heart-of-hearts,
he meant the reverse, which is the worst sin that a university
teacher can commit).
In any event, if you read Erdman’s book, which shouldn’t take
more than a few hours, you should take care not to miss what he
says about the situation in the U.S. before the l987 share market
meltdown. This is because, unfortunately, a large part of his
comments are relevant at the present time, to include his claim
that capital spending is “The most potent force in our economy”.
On the basis of what we observe in the automobile industry, as
well as Feldstein’s prediction about consumer spending, the
(present) movements in the oil price – which Erdman regarded as
hardly more than a detail before Black Monday (October 19, 1987) –
might prove to be the straw that breaks the elephant’s back.
Barsky and Kilian take a cavalier view about physical
investment, citing among other things their disbelief in Professor
Ben Bernanke’s ‘bad news principle’, which the future Federal
Reserve boss applied to oil price shocks (1983). What this comes
down to is firms postponing investment “as they attempt to find
out whether the increase in the price of oil is transitory or
permanent”.
Although Barsky and Kilian say that evidence exists that
Bernanke’s “waiting” effect is small relative to the magnitudes
that need to be explained, I doubt whether this contention
deserves to be treated with excessive respect when trying to
assess the economic future. The real price of oil (as compared to
the money or nominal price) has been constant or falling for the
last 30 years, and until recently the great majority of energy
professionals interested in oil have preached from every soapbox
between Lapland and the Capetown naval yard that both real and
nominal prices of oil were certain to decline. As a result many
firms have been quick to take advantage of what they judged to be
decent investment opportunities. In the light of oil price
increases over the past two years, however, many or most of these
firms are going to be more careful, which will tend to give extra
weight to expected bad news about energy prices.
Incidentally, Bernanke actually said that “of possible future
outcomes, only the unfavourable ones have a bearing on the current
propensity to undertake a given project”. This kind of thinking
ties in with a key postulate of real options theory: when waiting
is possible, downside risk is always the major factor.
WILL WE ENJOY AN UNDULATING PLATEAU?
A friend sent me a recent article by Ken Silverstein in
EnergyBiz Insider (2006) that dealt with the ‘peak oil’ issue.
Anyone desiring an insight into this topic should examine the
easily read contributions on oil in EnergyBiz and EnergyPulse, to
include the many comments on these articles that are also
published.
Perhaps the most provocative information recently offered in
that communication concerned the Cambridge Energy Research
Associates (CERA), whose director – Daniel Yergin – is a well
known energy commentator as well as a winner of the Pulitzer Prize
(for a book about oil titled ‘The Prize’). Apparently CERA doesn’t
believe in a global peaking of the oil production, but instead
claims to have theoretical and/or statistical proof that we will
eventually experience an undulating plateau. (Let me note though
that as a veteran teacher of game theory, I recognize the
possibility that in reality they may believe in a distinct peaking
of the world oil production even more than I do.)
In any event, there were no undulating plateaux in the U.S.,
UK, Russia, etc, and so the question should be asked why should
one be expected on a global level? The answer to that query is
that even if one is unlikely, it is still hypothetically possible,
but under no circumstances should anyone believe that a
statistical or econometric model could be constructed which is
capable of making this outcome explicit. Half-baked, but well
remunerated deception is what we are dealing with here – unless,
possibly, some political elements are put into the equations. This
extension cannot be broached in the present short paper, but it
should not be overlooked that the owners of Middle East oil now
understand that from a purely economic point of view, they are at
long last in the driver’s seat, which has or will offend some very
serious clients. Ignoring this departure, both geological and
economic logic point toward an eventual peak in Middle East
output, which in turn will ensure a peak in the global output.
Somewhat like Lee Strasberg in Godfather 2, I am a partially
retired teacher living on a small pension. In contrast to that
gentleman, however, I am not concerned with the ambitions of the
Corleones, or even the pretentious research mafia languishing in
certain faculties of economics in this country. My attention just
now is focussed on my modest portfolio. Along with Paul Erdman, I
became aware in the mid-1980s that a Black instead of a Green
Trading Day was on the horizon, and like the best financial
journalists in today’s media, I’m certain that a less drastic
replay of that trauma should not be excluded.
As pointed out above, it appears that an economist with the
prestige of Martin Feldstein has also become a Cassandra. (In case
you don’t remember, Cassandra really did have the gift of
prophecy, but it was her fate not to be believed.) It thus seems
useful to call attention to what happened in l982, following the
Iranian Revolution: unemployment in the U.S. reached 10%,
employment actually fell for a few months, and some interest rates
briefly exceeded 20%. Accordingly, some of us neither want to
suffer or witness again the kind of unpleasantness that bad
economic luck is capable of imposing.
REFERENCES
Banks, Ferdinand E. (2001). Global Finance and Financial
Markets. London, New York, and Singapore: World Scientific.
_____ . (2000). Energy Economics: A Modern Introduction. New
York: Kluwer Academ. Barsky, Robert B. and Lutz Kilian (2004).
‘Oil and the Macroeconomy since the l970s’. Journal of Economic
Perspectives (Fall).
Bernanke, Ben S. (1983). ‘Irreversibility, Uncertainty, and
cyclical investment’. Quarterly Journal of Economics. (February).
Erdman, Paul (1988). What’s Next? New York: Bantam Books.
Feldstein, Martin (2006). ‘America will fall harder if oil
prices rise again’. Financial Times (February 3).
Silverstein, Ken (2006). ‘Peak oil: real or not?’. EnergyBiz
Insider. (February)
http://www.energycentral.com/centers/energybiz
To join in on the conversation or to subscribe or visit
this site go to: http://www.energypulse.net
Copyright 2005 CyberTech, Inc.
|