Renewable Energy Portfolios Standards and Transmission
Reliability, Part IV
Location: New York
Author: George Campbell
Date: Friday, February 1, 2008
Most economists believe that they can solve any problem with the right mix
of incentives. They dream them up and implement them, study their results,
and then reshape them. Many economists believe the world has not yet
invented a problem that cannot be fixed if given a free hand to design the
proper incentive scheme. The solution may not always be pretty—often
involving coercion—but the original problem can be fixed. If demand response
is to play a large role in solving renewable portfolio standard's (RPS)
reliability problems, finding the right mix needs to take place (review my
first two articles in this series on RPS reliability problems Part I & Part
II.
In Part III of this series, I outline the three broad categories of
incentives that can be used to solve the demand response (DR) problem:
Financial Incentives, Moral Incentives and Mandatory Incentives. Given the
right mix of these three incentive types, I believe that the DR problem can
also be solved. To help understand how the three interact, I am going to use
an example from the international best selling book, Freakonomics, which is
a summary of some of University of Chicago economist Steven Levitt's
research on incentives. While the whole book provides a framework on how to
frame questions and seek answers to solve this problem, I am going to use
his example of an Israeli daycare center.
Parents picking up children late have always been a problem of daycare
centers. A pair of Israeli economists who heard of this common dilemma
offered a solution: charge an additional fee to the tardy parents. The
economists decided to test their solution by conducting a study of ten
daycare centers in Haifa, Israel. The study lasted twenty weeks, but the
additional fee was not introduced immediately. For the first four weeks, the
economists simply kept track of the number of parents who came late; there
were, on average, eight late pickups per week per daycare center. In the
fifth week, the fee was enacted. It was announced that any parent arriving
more than ten minutes late would pay $3 per child for each incident. The fee
would be added to the parents' monthly bill, which was roughly $380. After
the new fee was enacted, the number of late pickups promptly went up. Before
long there were twenty late pickups per week, more than double the original
average. The incentive had plainly backfired. So, what was wrong with the
incentive at the Israeli day-care centers? The $3 fee was simply too small.
For that price, a parent with one child could afford to be late every day
and only pay an extra $60 each month—just one-sixth of the base fee. The
problem with the day-care center late fee was it substituted a Financial
Incentive of $3 for a Moral Incentive (the guilt that parents were supposed
to feel when they came late). For just a few dollars each day, parents could
buy off their guilt. Furthermore, the small size of the fee sent a signal to
the parents that late pickups weren't such a big problem. All of us know how
the day care markets of the world solved this problem as we have experienced
parents abruptly leaving meetings at the end of the day to avoid very high
late fees. I have heard of some late fees that are so high and parents with
few other options that they go from being a Financial Incentive to a de
facto Mandatory Incentive.
Any incentive structure is a trade-off of these three types of incentives.
If DR is to grow in the United States, it will require the right complement
of Financial, Moral, and Mandatory Incentives. Financial Incentives have
been the mainstay of the DR incentive structure to date and will continue to
be. Every time a transmission operator or distribution utility calls for
voluntary load curtailment during peak times and customers curtail load, a
Moral Incentives is used. However, Mandatory Incentives have not been used
extensively and if DR is to significantly expand in its utilization,
understanding how to use it in compliment with the first two will need to
take place.
Examples of Mandatory Incentives in the electric utility industry are
numerous. At the Federal level in the last quarter of a century they can be
viewed as major segments starting with the Public Utility Regulatory Policy
Act (PURPA) of 1978 and the Energy Policy Acts of 1992 and 2005. These laws
set in motion the unbundling of generation as a monopoly and opened the
transmission system to bulk power sales. Most states have also implemented
Mandatory Incentives for a number of competitive market measures and to
solve environmental and social issues, such as recent renewable portfolio
standards that have been implemented in twenty five states. At the federal
level, DR has had no Mandatory Incentives implemented. This is probably the
result of federal law delegating retail electric oversight to state
authority and the FERC not regulating retail sales. At the State level, I
can only identify a few DR Mandatory Incentives and most of them could be
considered a secondary effect. The one I have written about most is the
requiring of default service for large C&I customers based on the wholesale
electric spot market.
So, what are the ranges of options for Mandatory DR Incentives? I group them
into the following:
* Compulsatory Customer Reductions: Requires customers to reduce a certain
amount of electric usage at the request of an entity with penalizing
authority for non compliance.
* Obligatory End-Use Control: Requires certain end usages of electricity to
be used during off peak times.
* Obligatory Facility Equipment: Requires retail customers to install
equipment in their facilities that has the capability to support DR.
* Distribution Utility Requirements: Requires Retail Electric Distribution
utilities to implement measures that promote the expansion of DR and will
complement their Financial or Moral DR Incentives.
To implement Compulsatory Customer Reductions for retail electric users will
entail the following:
1. Metering capable of measuring short-term energy consumption intervals;
2. Communication systems to notify customers of curtailment requirements;
and,
3. A regulatory agency to establish customer specific curtailment amounts,
set penalties and enforce non-compliance.
The metering infrastructure for measurement of a Compulsatory Customer
Reduction incentive is already in place for a large segment of the US's
commercial and industrial (C&I) customers. There are also many options for
the DR communication technology. Both of these first two infrastructure
needs are also needed to manage existing Financial DR Incentives type
programs and would be easy to transfer to Compulsatory Customer Reductions.
Enforcement of a mandatory requirement to curtail load would be very similar
to enforcement of customers on present voluntary interruptible programs. The
hurdle to a mandatory reduction requirement is that a central planning
process will be needed to determine how much every customer will curtail and
for what types of transmission reliability needs will trigger the
curtailment. Because individual retail customers have a broad range of
compliance cost and curtailment potential, Compulsatory Customer Reductions
will require the central administration function to allocate different
curtailment requirements towards different customers to ensure that there
are economic efficiency gains. It is my opinion that Mandatory Incentives of
this type have a high potential to decreased economic efficiency. They
should be one of the last to be considered. Before it is implemented it
should be studied under controlled conditions. Also other types of Mandatory
Incentives that do not have a high potential to decrease economic efficiency
should be implemented first.
Obligatory End-Use Control requires certain end usages of electricity to
incorporate DR. It has the potential to increase DR, especially in areas
which already have existing building inspectors that are already enforcing
other codes. For example, a building code would only allow controlled water
heating and the customer could put in dual fuel systems or a larger storage
tank so that there would not be deterioration in service quality. Another
example is the plug-in hybrid car and only allowing charging under a DR
controlled electric charge.
An example of a DR Obligatory Facility Equipment requirement for customer
facilities is an Energy Management Systems (EMS) to control heating,
ventilating, air conditioning and refrigeration equipment for residential,
commercial and industrial buildings. This building requirement could also
accomplish another social goal of energy efficiency. These last two types of
Mandatory DR Incentives should be evaluated in conjunction with Financial
and Moral DR Incentives. In addition they can be incorporated into broader
incentive structures to improve energy efficiency. In addition there are
many types of controls for residential appliance controls that could be
installed as part of standard features.
There are many examples of Distribution Utility Requirements. As part of an
IRP process, State Regulatory Commissions can require rebates for an EMS or
other DR enabling equipment. However, the one I believe would be most
effective is to require all large C&I customers to take default service
under rates that represent the wholesale electric spot energy and capacity
prices. (See Part III of this series).
To help solve the reliability problems that RPS will create will require
getting the "right mix" of these three incentive types. The "right mix" will
always require fine tuning and will also be different by region and will
change as the regional portfolio of supply side resources change as well as
customer end-use technology evolves. The solution is definitely not static.
My goal in this series is to start laying out the framework to identify the
range of DR incentive options.
UtiliPoint's IssueAlert(SM) articles are compiled based on
the independent analysis of UtiliPoint consultants. The opinions expressed
in UtiliPoint's IssueAlert articles are not intended to predict financial
performance of companies discussed, or to be the basis for investment
decisions of any kind. UtiliPoint's sole purpose in publishing its
IssueAlert articles is to offer an independent perspective regarding the key
events occurring in the energy industry, based on its long-standing
reputation as an expert on energy issues. © 2004, UtiliPoint International,
Inc. All rights reserved. This article is protected by United States
copyright and other intellectual property laws and may not be reproduced,
rewritten, distributed, redisseminated, transmitted, displayed, published or
broadcast, directly or indirectly, in any medium without the prior written
permission of UtiliPoint International, Inc.
|