February 5, 2009
Tax Reform and Community Based Renewable Energy
by John Farrell, ILSR
The federal tax credits for renewable energy have been a major barrier to
widespread ownership of renewable energy. The production tax credit, for
example, can only be taken against passive income, a type of income that
very few of us actually earn. Accelerated depreciation or investment tax
credits can be taken against ordinary income – slightly better – but again
the credit provides more benefit the higher one's tax bracket and the more
tax liability one has. The overhead costs in aggregating sufficient tax
equity to finance wind and solar projects have proven very high.
Nevertheless, to date the industry has grown rapidly based on this
inefficient and cumbersome arrangement.
The economic downturn, however, has all but eliminated the ability of
renewable energy projects to sell their tax credits. The result is that in
mid-January, AWEA and SEIA joined an increasing call to move toward
refundable tax credits.
This is a useful step, for it opens up the possibility of investments in
renewable energy from a much wider portion of the American people. But it is
only a halfway step. It will apply to the production tax credit but probably
not to the other types of tax benefits — accelerated depreciation and
investment tax credits. Thus similar overhead costs in selling tax
liabilities will occur and local ownership will still be stunted.
A better solution would be to avoid the need for tax incentives completely
and set a price utilities have to pay for renewable energy sufficient to
attract investors. Since investors would earn their money from the sale of
electricity, not the sale of tax credits, a majority of Americans might be
able to become investors.
The strategy is called a feed-in tariff (FIT). It has achieved remarkable
success in Europe and has now been adopted by one Canadian province
(Ontario) and one U.S. municipal utility in Gainesville, Florida. Half a
dozen states are currently considering such a strategy.
Under a FIT, the government or public utility commission sets the price for
renewable electricity high enough to attract investment. The price is varied
to achieve multiple goals. For example, a government might prefer to
encourage, with a higher price, rooftop solar rather than remote solar power
plants. It might prefer to encourage, with a higher price, emerging
technologies.
Utilities must enter into long-term (usually 20-year) contracts with the
producer. The government revisits the tariff price every couple of years,
lowering it when it feels producers are making excess profits, raising it
when insufficient production is occurring.
Many Americans may react in horror at the idea of government setting a
price. But in fact, that is the way the electric system has worked for more
than a century. Regulatory commissions offer a utility a guaranteed rate of
return sufficient to attract investment in new power plants.
Indeed, the U.S. now has two types of price setting. For conventional power
plants utilities are given a cost-plus contract. Ratepayers will pay a price
that recovers the cost of the power plant plus a healthy but reasonable
profit. For renewable energy plants, however, we cobble together a byzantine
array of tax benefits, rebates and mandates.
Some 38 states have renewable electricity mandates. In these states,
government sets the quantity and the "market" sets the price, with the
market massaged by tax and other incentives. Under a feed in tariff the
government sets the price and the "market" the quantity. Neither is a pure
market based strategy. But the feed-in tariff is much more transparent,
comprehensible and — studies have shown — less expensive and more effective.
At a conference on feed-in tariffs held by the Institute for Local
Self-Reliance in Minnesota in early January, former Minister of Energy of
the German state of Schleswig-Holstein, Willi Voigt said that the renewable
energy debate in the U.S. today sounds exactly like it did in Germany ten
years ago. It was around that time that their experimentation with various
renewable energy incentives gave way to a feed-in tariff. The renewable
energy industry immediately took off. Renewable energy generators today
satisfy 15 percent of German electricity needs. Half of the renewable energy
power plants are locally owned.
The Germans are exceeding their renewable energy goals at a cost less than
that of other European countries that have imitated U.S. strategies.
American renewable energy generators face increased risk and cost from
bundling energy incentives, confronted with the possible expiration of tax
incentives, and having to find equity partners. German producers can attract
low-cost financing because their electricity contract is guaranteed, the
price is attractive and the process of gaining interconnection approval is
simple and fast. German renewable energy policy also results in more
economic development (and green jobs), because more than half of projects
are locally owned.
Shifting to refundable tax credits is a good step, but the country and the
renewable energy industry would do better to demand a new way of doing
things. As our newly inaugurated president has suggested, we should set our
sights higher.
John Farrell is a research associate at the
Institute for Local
Self-Reliance, where he examines the benefits of local ownership in
renewable energy. His latest paper, Wind and Ethanol: Economies and
Diseconomies of Scale, uncovers why bigger isn't necessarily better. He's a
graduate of the University of Minnesota's Humphrey Institute of Public
Affairs and currently resides in Minneapolis, Minnesota.
To subscribe or visit go to:
http://www.renewableenergyaccess.com
|